What's new

Xinjiang people over 60 enjoy pension insurance benefits even if they haven’t paid fees or insuffici

Even in Singapore or the United States (they are all high-income countries), serious illnesses (such as cancer, heart, kidney, liver transplant, etc. are also very important household expenditures, and even need to sell houses).

In Singapore if your insurance isn't enough to cover the bills, there's a final layer of safety net from the state called the Medifund for those in need. The approval rate is 99%.

https://www.moh.gov.sg/docs/librari...ional-resources/building-a-healthy-nation.pdf

In your province, such as Heilongjiang or Qinghai, social security funds are already negative. There are still many balances in Shanghai or Guangdong social security funds. How can the government allocate funds? Shanghai people are not willing to give their surplus funds to Heilongjiang.

That's exactly the point. Provinces like Heilongjiang export young migrant workers to places like Guangdong. It's a major factor why there's such a huge difference in dependency ratio between provinces. In Guangdong, 9 workers support 1 retiree. In HLJ, it's almost 1:1.

36f25146756f48e0b500fa53f8f85666.jpeg


Places like Guangdong are benefiting at the expense of HLJ. It's an imbalance which will get only more unequal over time without the central government's intervention, because everyone wants to move to the prosperous coastal cities.
 
.
In Singapore if your insurance isn't enough to cover the bills, there's a final layer of safety net from the state called the Medifund for those in need. The approval rate is 99%.

https://www.moh.gov.sg/docs/librari...ional-resources/building-a-healthy-nation.pdf



That's exactly the point. Provinces like Heilongjiang export young migrant workers to places like Guangdong. It's a major factor why there's such a huge difference in dependency ratio between provinces. In Guangdong, 9 workers support 1 retiree. In HLJ, it's almost 1:1.

36f25146756f48e0b500fa53f8f85666.jpeg


Places like Guangdong are benefiting at the expense of HLJ. It's an imbalance which will get only more unequal over time without the central government's intervention, because everyone wants to move to the prosperous coastal cities.
In Singapore if your insurance isn't enough to cover the bills, there's a final layer of safety net from the state called the Medifund for those in need. The approval rate is 99%.

https://www.moh.gov.sg/docs/librari...ional-resources/building-a-healthy-nation.pdf



That's exactly the point. Provinces like Heilongjiang export young migrant workers to places like Guangdong. It's a major factor why there's such a huge difference in dependency ratio between provinces. In Guangdong, 9 workers support 1 retiree. In HLJ, it's almost 1:1.

36f25146756f48e0b500fa53f8f85666.jpeg


Places like Guangdong are benefiting at the expense of HLJ. It's an imbalance which will get only more unequal over time without the central government's intervention, because everyone wants to move to the prosperous coastal cities.
rich country, rich pension treatment!
 
. .
rich country, rich pension treatment!

Not exactly. Total healthcare expenditure is actually very low in Singapore, compared to other countries. Just that we are more efficient with our unique hybrid system. We are spend half as much as the OECD average and yet deliver better results.

https://www.vox.com/policy-and-politics/2017/4/25/15356118/singapore-health-care-system-explained

Is Singapore’s “miracle” health care system the answer for America?

When liberals talk about their health care utopia, they have scores of examples to choose from. Some name France’s high-performing multi-payer system (No. 1 on the World Health Organization’s rankings, in case you haven’t heard). Others point to Canada’s single-payer simplicity. The Scandinavian countries all do health care well, and there’s much to recommend Germany’s hybrid approach.

Conservatives really only have one example of a free market health care paradise to point to: Singapore. But oh, what an example it is! In a New York Times column called “Make America Singapore,” Ross Douthat called it “the marvel of the wealthy world.” After the election, Fox News published an op-ed headlined, "Want to ditch ObamaCare? Let's copy Singapore's health care miracle.”

Why are conservatives so taken with Singapore? The American Enterprise Institute’s glowing write-up explains it well:

What’s the reason for Singapore’s success? It’s not government spending. The state, using taxes, funds only about one-fourth of Singapore’s total health costs. Individuals and their employers pay for the rest. In fact, the latest figures show that Singapore’s government spends only $381 (all dollars in this article are U.S.) per capita on health—or one-seventh what the U.S. government spends.

Singapore’s system requires individuals to take responsibility for their own health, and for much of their own spending on medical care.

Here’s what Singapore’s conservative admirers get right: Singapore really is the only truly universal health insurance system in the world based on the idea that patients, not insurers, should bear the costs of routine care.

But Singapore isn’t a free market utopia. Quite the opposite, really. It’s a largely state-run health care system where the government designed the insurance products with a healthy appreciation for free market principles — the kind of policy Milton Friedman might have crafted if he’d been a socialist.

Unlike in America, where the government’s main role is in managing insurance programs, Singapore’s government controls and pays for much of the medical system itself — hospitals are overwhelmingly public, a large portion of doctors work directly for the state, patients can only use their Medisave accounts to purchase preapproved drugs, and the government subsidizes many medical bills directly.

What Singapore shows is that unusual fusions of conservative and liberal ideas in health care really are possible. Singapore is a place where the government acts to keep costs low and then uses those low costs to make a market-driven insurance system possible. One thing you quickly realize when studying their system is it would be a disaster if you tried to impose it in a country with America’s out-of-control medical prices.

That speaks to the more depressing lesson of Singapore. As soon as you begin seriously comparing where they are, and how their system works, to where the US is, and how our system works, it becomes painfully clear how far America is from having the institutions or preconditions for truly radical health care reform.

How Singapore’s health insurance system works
Books could be written on the structure of Singapore’s health care system, and indeed, they have been. Jeremy Lim’s Myth or Magic: The Singapore Healthcare System is particularly excellent, though William Haseltine’s Affordable Excellence: The Singapore Healthcare Story has the advantage of being free. A deep dive here is rewarding, and my summary will necessarily oversimplify.

But the basic structure of Singapore’s insurance system is built around the “three M’s”: Medisave, Medishield, and Medifund. Let’s take them in turn.

Medisave: When conservatives praise Singapore’s health system, they are typically praising the Medisave system. Medisave is a forced savings plan that consumes between 7 and 9.5 percent of a working Singaporean’s wages — think of it like the Social Security payroll tax, if said tax funded a health savings account. Singaporeans then pay for some routine care out of their Medisave accounts.

Conservatives like Medisave because it is built on a deep appreciation for the idea that routine medical care can be treated like any other good, and patients can be pushed to act like consumers when buying it. Which is all true. Medisave distinguishes Singapore’s system from that of the US or Western Europe, where insurers typically cover most of the cost of routine care.

But again, the way Medisave actually works is the government forces you to divert 7 to 9.5 percent of your wages into this account, and then it decides what you can do with those savings — one way Singapore keeps drug prices low, for instance, is it only allows Medisave funds to be used for drugs that the government judges cost-effective (more on this later).

So while Medisave may look like a health savings account, it’s a mandatory health savings account funded by a payroll tax and only usable in certain conditions.

Medishield: Not all medical care is routine care. For the big expenses, Singapore runs Medishield, a nationwide catastrophic insurance program. The premiums are set by your age, and the deductibles are reasonably high — roughly $1,400 in US dollars. Enrollment is automatic, though you can opt out if you choose.

Together, Medishield and Medisave form the core of Singapore’s more market-oriented health insurance system — the idea is you pay routine expenses out of your Medisave account, and if things get bad enough that you hit your deductible, you begin using your Medishield account. This accords with the broader conservative view on health care: Insurance should cover unexpected costs, and for everything else, people should shop around as they do for most other products, and unleash the powers of the market.

But to make that structure work, Singapore relies on a massive amount of government coercion across the entire system. Fully funding your Medisave account is compulsory, not optional. You’re automatically enrolled in Medishield. The government limits the services both programs can purchase and, as we’ll see, often produces or reprices the services both programs purchase.

Medifund: Some Singaporeans fall through the cracks of Medisave and Medishield. For them, there’s Medifund — Singapore’s payer-of-last-resort.

Medifund’s structure is unusual in two ways. First, it’s based on a $3 billion endowment, with the government only able to spend the previous year’s investment income to pay for the needy’s medical bills; dipping into the endowment itself is forbidden. Second, it’s administered with a lot of discretion at the hospital level — so rather than qualifying for Medifund based on income, the way Americans do for Medicaid, hospital boards administer Medifund to the patients they judge needy enough to qualify. This is less restrictive than it might sound — the government says that more than 99 percent of applications are approved.

The big vulnerability of Medifund is that a bad investment year could wipe out the government’s ability to pay — and do so at the moment it was most needed. It’s a testament to Singapore’s economy, and to the government’s fiscal skill, that they’ve not faced this problem yet.

How Singapore’s health care system works
It’s easy, looking at Singapore’s insurance scheme, to see what conservatives find so attractive in the system. While there’s significant coercion, there’s also a real focus on pushing patients to act like consumers, and reserving insurance for unexpected, unusual costs. In addition, Singapore’s safety net — Medifund — is limited in its commitments and administered at the local level.

But all that happens within the context of a government-controlled — and often government-run — medical system.

This is a key difference between Singapore and America. The bulk of the American government’s intervention into the health care system is done through health insurance, and so American analysts often look at Singapore’s insurance system and stop there. But the bulk of the Singapore government’s intervention into the health care system is through the health care system itself.

Take the way the two countries subsidize medical care. In America, insurance is often subsidized — by paying the bills of Medicare or Medicaid enrollees, by giving tax credits to Obamacare enrollees and employer-sponsored health plans. In Singapore, medical treatment itself is subsidized.

More than 80 percent of the hospital beds in Singapore are in public hospitals, and those hospitals are cut into different “wards” with different levels of amenities: A-class wards provide unsubsidized care but have single rooms and air conditioning, while C-class wards are overwhelmingly subsidized but are set up like shared dormitories with common toilets. There are a number of ward levels in between, too, all with a sliding scale of comfort and subsidization. So both A-ward patients and C-ward patients are paying for their own care, but the prices they’re paying are very, very different, because the government is absorbing the direct cost of care in the C-wards.

These subsidies remain a huge part of the country’s overall health spending. In 2009, the 3 M’s only financed 23 percent of total inpatient care; by contrast, government subsidies accounted for 51 percent. (It’s worth noting that government subsidies are a lot less prominent in primary care.)

The government’s subsidies are designed to do more than simply make care affordable — they’re also designed to shape patient and provider decisions and influence pricing. “The policies around what services to subsidize, how much to subsidize, who to subsidize and what providers and patients need to do in exchange for subsidy eligibility, make subsidies one of the most impactful tools in the Ministry of Health’s policy armamentarium,” Lim writes.

Take pharmaceuticals. In 2009, Americans spent $947 per person on drugs. Singaporeans spent merely $389. A major way the Singaporean government holds down drug prices is deciding which drugs are eligible for subsidies and Medisave spending.

The Singaporean Ministry of Health publishes a “standard drug list.” These are drugs the government believes to be “cost-effective and essential.” Drugs on that list are provided at subsidized rates to patients. The government also decides which drugs can be bought with Medisave funds. Drugs that don’t appear on either list may still be available in hospitals, but at prohibitive prices.

Singapore is unusually secretive about how its pharmaceutical decisions are made — Britain’s much-criticized National Institute for Health and Care Excellence, which makes decisions about which drugs will qualify for public funds, is far more transparent. A previous health minister of Singapore says the opacity is to prevent “intense lobbying by pharmaceutical companies” — what they want are pharmaceutical companies selling all drugs at low prices in the hopes of getting onto the standard list. That’s how Singapore uses their subsidies to lower prices not just for the subsidized but for everyone.

Compare all this with America, where Medicare is prohibited, by law, from negotiating down the price of pharmaceuticals, even for its own enrollees!

One lesson of Singapore: everything is easier when costs are lower
According to the World Bank, in 2014 Singapore spent $2,752 per person on health care. America spent $9,403. Given this, it’s worth asking a few questions about what Singapore’s model really has to teach the US.

Are Singaporeans really more exposed to health costs than Americans? The basic argument for the Singaporean system is that Singaporeans, through Medisave and the deductibles in Medishield, pay more of the cost of their care, and so hold costs down. Americans, by contrast, have their care paid for by insurers and employers and the government, and so they have little incentive to act like shoppers and push back on prices. But is that actually true?

I doubt it. The chasm in total spending is the first problem. Health care prices are so much lower in Singapore that Singaporeans would have to pay for three times more of their care to feel as much total expense as Americans do. Given the growing size of deductibles and copays in the US, I doubt that’s true now, if it ever was. (It’s worth noting that, on average, Singaporeans are richer than Americans, so the issue here is not that we have more money to blow on health care.)

According to Singapore’s data, in 2008 cash and Medisave financed a bit less than half of the system’s total costs. Let’s say, generously, that’s $1,200 in annual spending. According to the Kaiser Family Foundation, the average deductible in employer health plans is now $1,478 — and that’s to say nothing of premiums, copays, etc. And of course, average deductibles outside the employer market are much, much higher.

Singapore’s system is probably better designed in terms of how consumers spend their own money. But the lower overall prices make them much less exposed to health costs than both patients and employers inside the American system — which suggests to me that Americans have at least as much incentive as Singaporeans to try to use their power as consumers to cut costs.

The fact that that hasn’t worked is, I think, a reason to believe we’ve gotten the lesson of Singapore’s health system backward. Singapore heavily regulates both the pricing and provision of medical care to keep costs low (as do all other developed countries) and then, working off that baseline of low costs, has Singaporeans pay out of pocket in order to keep them mindful of how much they’re spending.

In America, conservatives want to apply that strategy in reverse: working off a baseline of extremely high prices, they want to force people to pay out of pocket as a strategy to bring those prices down. That hasn’t worked so far, and my guess is efforts to double down on it — of which the Republican Obamacare alternative is one — will continue to fail.

What would happen if you brought Singapore’s system to the US? Spend a moment imagining a transition to a Singapore-like system in the US, given our prices. With per capita health spending over $9,000, we would need to force people to save far more than Singapore’s paltry 7 to 9.5 percent of monthly wages to build reasonable health savings accounts (remember, children and the elderly don’t earn much, and so need their expenses covered by their family’s savings).

A policy like this would make Obamacare’s individual mandate look gentle. Remember, the mandate doesn’t even apply if you can’t find a comprehensive health insurance plan that costs less than 8 percent of your household income. Here, you’d be forced to save more than 8 percent of household income, and that’s just for the part of the system managing out-of-pocket costs for routine care.

Which is all to say that there are a lot of program designs that are possible when health care is cheap, and very few that are possible when health care is as expensive as it is in the United States. Admirers of Singapore’s system often reverse the causality of their experiment: The Singaporean system is possible because the government keeps costs so low. If prices rose to US levels, their system wouldn’t be possible, as the out-of-pocket costs would lead to revolt.

Oh, and everything else in Singapore is different too
One difficulty with comparing anything in Singapore to anything anywhere else is Singapore is very, very weird.

It’s a city-state of 6 million people that’s only been governing itself since about 1960. Though elections are now considered broadly free in Singapore, power has only ever been held by one party — in part because that party has proven itself perhaps the most successful group of technocrats in human history. Singapore has gone from a poor country in the 1950s to holding the third highest per capita income today.

In part for that reason, trust in the government is extraordinarily high, and the government wields that power aggressively. Singapore’s health outcomes are excellent, but that’s not only because its health system is well-designed. Singapore manages a nanny state beyond anything Americans can imagine, or would permit.

Despite the country’s wealth, only 15 percent of Singaporeans have cars, because the government makes car ownership prohibitively expensive. There’s virtually no illegal drugs or gun crime in Singapore, in part because drug dealers are executed and guns are outlawed. Cigarette and alcohol taxes are enormous by American standards. As Matt Yglesias said in our episode of The Weeds discussing Singapore, “If you imagine America with no guns, less booze, much less drugs, and radically less driving, our public health outcomes would soar.”

There’s much America could learn from Singapore. But the lessons need to be taken in whole. The Singaporean system is unusually good at applying market forces to routine health expenses. But that happens within a context where the government is aggressively managing the supply of health services, the price of treatments, and the broader behavioral environment in which the system operates. Singapore’s health care system relies much more on the government, and much less on the market, than America’s does.

Which is not to say liberals should be confident about adopting Singapore’s model either. America is far from having the kinds of low costs or faith in public institutions needed to replicate Singapore’s “miracle.”

A point that both Lim and Haseltine make in their books is that the Singaporean government has sought to keep control of the health system because leaders’ study of other countries persuaded them that once costs and medical interest groups grew out of control, the government could no longer effectively regulate the system. Quoting a former Singaporean health minister, Haseltine writes, “f the public healthcare system is too small, it becomes the ‘tail that tries to wag the dog.’ Once a private healthcare system becomes the dominant entrenched player, it is very difficult to unwind it — there are many vested interests and many pockets will be hurt.”

In America, the private health care system is the dominant entrenched player. And that makes radical reform, either toward a Singapore-like system or toward any other public-driven system, very, very difficult. There’s much you can imagine designing if we were starting from scratch, but it’s very challenging to design high-performing, clean systems that we could smoothly transition to from here, given how many hospitals and doctors and employers and even patients are dependent on the money flowing through system we have, and would viciously fight efforts to upend it.

little country, huge country, different situation.

If you have the time, do watch this.


They tried Singapore's system in the state of Indiana for state employees and the result proved better.
 
.
. .
1)In China, public servants enjoy medical privileges, do not need to queue up for medical treatment, have special medical areas and wards, and all expenses are reimbursed. Although these benefits are also reduced, it is an indisputable fact that Chinese public servants enjoy medical privileges. This is why so many People want to be civil servants, I have also participated civil servant exams, but unfortunately failed for various reasons.
2)
For my grandfather and my grandmother's generation (the illiterate who can't write), can get the pension subsidy from the government and get the medical insurance treatment.they can never believe it in their wild dreams.
Therefore, I said that we must look at the issue from a development perspective. In other countries, a policy will remain unchanged for 30 or even 50 years. In China, because of China’s rapid development, China’s policies may changed a lot in three years and tremendously in five years.
In a word, the lives of Chinese people are improving day by day.

If you have the time, do watch this.
All i see is blank
.
 
Last edited:
. .
They tried Singapore's system in the state of Indiana for state employees and the result was better.


The article? I've quoted it in full.
Indiana? US state?Come on,you want to compare the pension insurance level of a 60000 USD per capita economy with a 9900 USD per capita economy?
 
.
Indiana? US state?Come on,you want to compare the pension insurance level of a 60000 USD per capita economy with a 9900 USD per capita economy?

Just watch. I'm not talking about implementing Singapore's system in China or the US.
 
.
Good news: Xinjiang poor people over 60 years old directly enjoy the pension insurance benefits, even if they have not paid the fees / or the payment period is insufficient
Xinjiang Network 2019-03-19 18:36:32
Since January 1st, 2019, Xinjiang's 60-year-old or older poor elderly who have not been insured or paid for a sufficient number of years can enjoy the pension insurance for urban and rural residents without paying premiums; before the end of September,all the poor people not be listed for insurance shall be included in the basic old-age insurance system for urban and rural residents.

2019 is the key year to win the battle against poverty.

On March 18th, a video conference on social security poverty alleviation and social insurance work in the autonomous region was held. At the meeting, this year, the autonomous region will adhere to the general tone of steady progress, strive to do a good job in social security poverty alleviation and central poverty alleviation, and pay attention to rectification and implementation, focus on preventing and defusing risks in social security, implement social security reform tasks, and continuously enhance the people. A sense of well-being, happiness and security.

Chen Baoping, director of the Rural Social Insurance Department of the Human Resources and Social Security Department of the Autonomous Region, said that this year, the work of poverty alleviation will be implemented, and the policy of poor people will be tilted. For those who have not paid or paid their fees for 15 years, and they are really unable to pay. Poor people over the age of 60 can receive the pension insurance for urban and rural residents without reimbursement; if they are under the age of 60, strictly implement the government payment policy for the urban and rural residents' pension insurance for the poverty-stricken population, and fully implement the policy. The basic endowment insurance for urban and rural residents of the poverty-stricken people should be guaranteed.

According to the three-year implementation plan of social security and poverty alleviation in the autonomous region from 2018 to 2020, the poor population will be included in the mandatory population of the national insurance plan. In 2018, the basic old-age insurance participation rate of the poverty-stricken population in the whole district is 98.47%, including the deep poverty-stricken counties. The basic old-age insurance participation rate of the poor population reached 99.22%. By the end of the year, among the poor people who met the conditions of participation in the whole district, the number of people enjoying the government's payment policy was 833,900, and the number of people enjoying the treatment was 533,700.

At the same time as doing the insurance work, the autonomous region will also improve the determination of the pension insurance for urban and rural residents and the normal adjustment mechanism for basic pensions, and steadily raise the basic pension level for urban and rural residents.

It is not only concentrated on promoting the full coverage of the pension insurance for the poverty-stricken population of the establishment of the card, the autonomous region will also accurately identify the uninsured personnel and the reasons for non-insurance in other groups, accurately lock out the insured personnel, screen the collection and payment and repeat the treatment. Personnel, targeted to promote the work of enrollment and enrollment of the whole people; expand the participation of small and medium-sized micro-enterprises workers, flexible employees, and new-employee practitioners to ensure that everyone is covered and covered.

good news! Xinjiang elderly people over 60 years old directly enjoy pension insurance benefits
continue reading

good news! Xinjiang elderly people over 60 years old directly enjoy pension insurance benefits
"One increase and one drop" to enhance the people's sense of happiness

The old-age pension insurance is also good news, and the sense of happiness and happiness of all ethnic groups is enhanced through “one increase and one decrease”.

On March 18th, a video conference on social security poverty alleviation and social insurance work in the autonomous region was held. The reporter learned from the meeting that the autonomous region will adhere to the general tone of seeking stability and promote the implementation of various social security policies.

In recent years, the pension treatment in the autonomous region has steadily increased. In 2018, the basic pension for enterprise retirees has been adjusted for the 14th time. The retirees of enterprises and institutions have been adjusted simultaneously for the third time. The overall adjustment level is 5.5%.

Sun Zhanxue, deputy director of the Endowment Insurance Department of the Human Resources and Social Security Department of the Autonomous Region, said that this year will continue to raise the basic pension for retirees, and the institutions, institutions and enterprises will adjust simultaneously, and the adjustment plan will be implemented after the country is officially clarified.

This year's National People's Congress's government work report clearly clarified: significantly reduce the burden of corporate social security contributions. The proportion of contributions paid by the basic endowment insurance units of urban employees will be lowered.

In accordance with the unified national deployment, the autonomous region will implement a comprehensive plan to reduce the social insurance rate and ensure the smooth operation of the fund. The burden of social security contributions for enterprises, especially small and micro enterprises, has declined substantially.

Sun Zhanxue said that this is to further reduce the social security contributions of enterprises on the basis of ensuring the smooth operation of the fund, not only to reduce the burden of corporate contributions, but also to ensure that the retirees’ treatment is not reduced, the pensions are reasonably grown and paid in full and on time, so that the social security fund can Sustained, the company benefits from it.

In 2018, the autonomous region's phased reduction of social insurance rates has achieved remarkable results. Continue to implement the phased reduction of social insurance premium rate policy, the proportion of basic pension insurance unit payment for enterprise employees is reduced to 19%; work injury insurance can be adjusted according to the number of months that each regional fund can pay, and the current rate will be adjusted by 20% to 50%; The sum of insurance units and individual contributions fell to 1%. In the year of social insurance, the company reduced the burden by 3.1 billion yuan.

In addition, the autonomous region will comprehensively promote the reform of the endowment insurance system for government agencies and institutions, and the staff of institutions and institutions that have gone through the retirement procedures after October 1, 2014 will be paid according to the new measures, and plans to implement them by the end of June.

Source: Xinjiang Network

https://www.toutiao.com/a6670048958682759687/
好消息!新疆60岁以上贫困老人直接享受养老保险待遇
新疆网 2019-03-19 18:36:32
自今年1月1日起,新疆60周岁以上因未参保或缴费不够年限的贫困老人可不用补费,直接享受城乡居民养老保险待遇;9月底前,将未参保建档立卡贫困人员全部纳入城乡居民基本养老保险制度。

2019年是打赢脱贫攻坚战的关键之年。

3月18日,自治区社保扶贫推进暨社会保险工作视频会议召开。会上提出,今年,自治区将坚持稳中求进工作总基调,全力做好社保扶贫和中央脱贫攻坚专项巡视反馈意见整改落实,着力防范和化解社保领域风险,落实社保改革任务,不断增强人民群众的获得感、幸福感和安全感。

自治区人力资源和社会保障厅农村社会保险处处长陈保平说,今年将做实做细社保扶贫工作,给予贫困人员政策倾斜,对未缴费或缴费未满15年、且本人确实无力缴费的年满60周岁以上贫困人员,可不用补费,直接领取城乡居民养老保险待遇;未满60周岁的,严格落实建档立卡贫困人口城乡居民养老保险个人缴费政府代缴政策,全面实现建档立卡贫困人员城乡居民基本养老保险应保尽保。

根据自治区2018-2020年社保扶贫攻坚战三年实施方案,贫困人口被纳入全民参保计划的必保人群,2018年全区建档立卡贫困人口基本养老保险参保率98.47%,其中深度贫困县贫困人口基本养老保险参保率达到99.22%,截至年底,全区符合参保条件贫困人员中,享受政府代缴政策人数83.39万人,享受待遇人数53.37万人。

在做好参保工作同时,自治区也将完善城乡居民养老保险待遇确定和基础养老金正常调整机制,稳步提高城乡居民养老保险基础养老金水平。

不仅仅是集中力量推进建档立卡贫困人口养老保险全覆盖,自治区也将精准识别其他人群中未参保人员和未参保原因,精准锁定中断缴费人员,筛查征缴缴费和重复领取待遇人员,针对性地推进全民参保扩面工作;扩大中小微企业职工、灵活就业人员、新业态从业人员等人群参保,实现人人参保、应保尽保。

继续阅读

“一增一降”增强群众获得感幸福感

自治区养老保险又有利好消息传出,通过“一增一降”增强各族群众的获得感、幸福感。

3月18日,自治区社保扶贫推进暨社会保险工作视频会议召开。记者从会上了解到,自治区将坚持稳中求进总基调,推进各项社保惠民政策落实。

近年来,自治区养老待遇稳步提高,2018年连续第14次调整企业退休人员基本养老金,企业和机关事业单位退休人员第3次同步调整,总体调整水平为5.5%。

自治区人力资源和社会保障厅养老保险处副处长孙战学说,今年将继续提高退休人员基本养老金,机关事业单位和企业同步调整,调整方案待国家正式明确后组织实施。

今年全国两会政府工作报告中明确:明显降低企业社保缴费负担。下调城镇职工基本养老保险单位缴费比例。

自治区将按照国家统一部署,稳妥实施降低社会保险费率综合方案,确保基金平稳运行,企业特别是小微企业社保缴费负担有实质性下降。

孙战学说,这是在确保基金平稳运行的基础上,进一步降低企业社保缴费支出,既减轻企业缴费负担,同时保证退休人员待遇不降低、养老金合理增长并按时足额发放,使社保基金可持续、企业与之共同受益。

2018年自治区阶段性降低社会保险费率成效显著。持续执行阶段性降低社会保险费率政策,企业职工基本养老保险单位缴费比例降低至19%;工伤保险根据各统筹地区基金可支付月数,在现行费率基础上下调20%至50%;失业保险单位和个人缴费总和降至1%。社会保险当年为企业减负31亿元。

另外,自治区将全面推进机关事业单位养老保险制度改革,对2014年10月1日之后办理退休手续的机关事业单位人员,按新办法计发待遇,计划在6月底前落实到位。

来源:新疆网
https://www.toutiao.com/a6670048958682759687/
This is a test for Muslims.

Iman vs monetary benefits.
 
. . .
Idiot. That's applicable to hindus or Sikhs.
You Indians say that Chinese people eat dog meat, aren't they?
In fact, China may has only 1 million people who eat dog meat, but in the eyes of Indians, due to Western propaganda, it has become 1.3 billion people among 1.4 billion people who do so.

Indians are not all Hindus or Sikhs, but the Chinese feel that as long as they are Indians, they will treat cows as gods and drink cow urine.
As you said, the Chinese central government has allocated funds to the Xinjiang government to improve the pension level of the elderly in Xinjiang.

In your eyes, it has become a test for Muslims.?
This policy is not only for Uighurs in Xinjiang, but all low-income people over 60 years old in Xinjiang, including Han, Uygur, Kazak, Hui, Kirgiz, Mongolian, Tajik, Xibo, Manchu, Uzbek, Turkmen, Russian, Daur, Tatar, etc.,all people with 60 yrs old age and with Chinese nationality in Xinjiangdirectly enjoy the pension insurance benefits, even if they have not paid the fees / or the payment period is insufficient.

Since When did the Mongolian Chinese and the Han Chinese became Muslims?
 
.
This is a human rights abuse according to india whose people are dying from hunger and turkey which is currently experiencing a recession.
 
.
Back
Top Bottom